| 41. | The counter-example was based on an asymmetrical utility function.
|
| 42. | A Cobb-Douglas utility function implies that goods are independent.
|
| 43. | A submodular utility function is characteristic of substitute goods.
|
| 44. | A supermoduler utility function is characteristic of complementary goods.
|
| 45. | But that depends on our individual utility functions.
|
| 46. | Indifference curve analysis begins with the utility function.
|
| 47. | This follows from continuity of the utility function.
|
| 48. | All consumers have the same Cobb-Douglas utility functions.
|
| 49. | Utility functions are also normally continuous functions.
|
| 50. | Every additive utility function is weakly-additive.
|